“The NFL has no incentive to
work out a deal with the real refs because demand for the game is inelastic.” –
Steve Young, on the Monday Night Football set directly following the infamous
Packers vs. Seahawks game.
Is it true? Does the NFL
really have no incentive to improve operations because demand for the game is
inelastic? According to the furor of ESPN analysts who suddenly discovered the
economic definition of “elasticity”, it certainly is true. If it is true, what
would prompt the NFL to change anything? If the same number of fans will watch
regardless, surely there is no incentive to ever improve operations. If, for
example, the ticket prices raised 100%, would you still attend the games? Surely
Steve Young knows what he’s saying. After all, he did graduate from BYU with
both his undergraduate and JD (of course, we all know BYU is the school where
they encourage a man to have multiple…utility curves).
Economicseducation |
First, let me define demand
elasticity in the context of economics. Demand elasticity is the percentage
change in demand over the percentage change for a certain variable. For
example, if the relative income for the market of an NFL team went up 10% and
ticket sales went up 20%, the income elasticity of demand is 2 or (20%/10%).
Since the elasticity is greater than 1, it is said to be elastic. If the
elasticity was less than 1, it’d be inelastic, and at exactly 1, it’s unit
elastic.
Now that we’ve completed our
economics 101 lesson for the day, let’s think back to my last blog where I
posited a reason that metropolitan GDP in college towns was uninfluenced by
team performance. I said this is because of relatively inelastic demand for
college football tickets. Given what we’ve just established as elasticity, that
seems like a reasonable enough conclusion now – at least I think. My conclusion effectively stated the
performance elasticity of demand was relatively inelastic, or maybe even nearly
perfectly inelastic in the short term, to where the same number of fans will
patron a team and its hometown businesses the same regardless of performance.
Here, though, I’m going to review this paradigm for the NFL and compare it to
college football through an equitable qualitative analysis.
In order to do this, let’s
first set some parameters. Now, when Steve Young made his remark, he was
referring to referee elasticity of demand. However, the influx of analysts who
suddenly seemed enthusiastic about this remark didn’t exactly understand this,
as they continually regurgitated their Wikipedia definitions of price
elasticity of demand. As such, here I’m going to compare only the price
elasticity of demand for the NFL and college football. Also, I’m aware the best
way to do this would be to gather exhaustive ticket price and attendance data,
run the regressions, and estimate elasticity. However, I’m going to assume
teams have already done this correctly and I’m going to infer the elasticity
from the behavior of the teams and corresponding pricing.
I made this graph, so don't say anything about the aesthetics! |
Ok, so first let’s tackle the NFL
(pun intended). In short, the NFL is NOT inelastic in terms of price and
demand. In a recent article on Yahoo!Finance, it was explained that NFL stadium
profits are hurting, and thus, teams are lowering ticket prices to elicit greater
profits. Assuming Steve Young was right and other kinds of demand in general is
inelastic (thereby assuming no demand curve shifts), this means NFL ticket
prices are elastic. If we observe the graph to the left, we’ll notice that
profit is maximized at unit elasticity, and thus, lowering prices means the NFL
was previously operating in the elastic portion of the demand curve (there
could be several other factors at play here, but remember, I’m assuming owners
have already controlled for these).
Next, let’s hit college football.
Based on my previous blog’s quantitative analysis, I’ll again assume general
demand is consistent and no shifts are imminent. As such, it is apparent price
elasticity of demand for college football is inelastic. Recent studies have
shown that college ticket prices have been steadily rising at abnormal rates
(adjusted for inflation, that is), and ticket sales remain incredibly high.
This may even suggest college football is nearly perfectly inelastic. Again, if
we consult our trusty graph above, we’ll see that raising ticket prices leads
to more profits in the inelastic portion of the demand curve (again, there
could be other factors, but I’m assuming they’re controlled).
So why does college football
get to enjoy price inelasticity and not the NFL? Brace yourself because I’m
about to hit you with some marketing here…it’s because of branding. People
often assert the NFL is tremendous and powerful brand. While this may be true,
its brand doesn’t hold a candle to college football. College football is able to connect with fans
at a much more intimate level, where many of the fans feel a VERY real sense of
belonging to the school. College football fans will base their entire year
around attending games, and will mortgage their lives to make sure to see top
rivalries. While people love the NFL, too, fans aren’t as concerned with
attending games. Very rarely do you see the connection between fans and NFL
teams that you do with college football teams. In fact, those NFL teams with
even a remotely passionate fan base are often compared to a “college football
atmosphere”. In that sense, college football has excelled at creating a
holistic that brands much more than just the game.
So what’s the lesson here?
Connect with your customers and you will control them (with prices at least).
Is that cynical?
No comments:
Post a Comment